Sustainable SRDs? – Report from a group discussion

“Sustaining the biosphere is not an ecological problem, nor a social problem, nor an economic problem. It is an integrated combination of all three.” (Holling, 1994)

“Sustainable SRDs? – Pros and Cons” was the theme of discussion in parallel working groups. This post reports from one of the group discussions that took place on the first day of our workshop. Instead of giving a complete report of the discussions, I would like to highlight some aspects that were of importance and interest to me. It intends stimulating debates and discussions on the blog by inviting the other participants of the working group to comment and amend the post.

The discussion in our breakout group continued the vivid exchange that took place during the plenaries. In a first step, each of the participants’ of this working group had the task to fill out cards and put them on the board. Already while presenting their cards and while hanging them on the wall, we started to discuss further details. In a second step, we rearranged the cards as to group them thematically. The discussion about sustainable SDRs centered on several topics:

To my view, a very interesting debate occurred about the tension between a possible funding for sustainable development transformations on the one hand and the risk of stimulating economic growth with negative externalities on the other. In a positive reading, one could argue that increasing SDRs would help raising money for the societal transformations towards sustainable development. One could imagine, for example, to issue with this newly create money the Green Climate Fund, which shall receive $100bn annually by 2020. Thereby, the creation of SDRs could help to finance sustainable development projects, to construct global central bank and pave ways for a global central regulation of financial markets.

However, as another participant objected, the raise of money has in the past rather stimulated economic growth instead of sustainable development. So far, economics growth has been closely related to increases in CO2 emissions, resource extraction and material consumption. In short, economics growth has shifted costs to both the ecological and social sphere (see also Kapp 1950).

Since many positive arguments for SDRs were found, one participant raised the very important question to analyze why its implementation did not take place yet. Via historical analysis of processes, institutions and influential people one could learn more about barriers and bridges towards implementing SDRs. Following this reasoning, another question raised concerns the geopolitics of SDRs, which are worth studying.

A call for more transdisciplinarity was clearly put forward as to involve the broader public in the often technical and complex discussions about a sustainable global financial system.

Given my background in ecological economic, I found the questions concerning ecological macroeconomics very interesting. Amongst this topic, not only the question of human development and well-being within planetary boundaries is of interest. How to create mechanisms to recycle the surplus? How to install fiat currencies that limit financial speculation? – These are only two examples of further research paths.

The question of sustainable SDRs remains still open. Some answers and many questions have been raised during the breakout group as documented here in a first step. I hope that the participants of our working group will pick up the topics and add further information from our lively debate.

Seven research questions on SDRs as a reserve currency

First of all I would like to express my personal thanks to speakers and participants in the workshop on a sustainable financial system and developed SDRs. The presentations and the discussions were thought-provoking and they showed the need for more reflections and research, which most certainly will be taken on board in the white paper that is the planned outcome of the conference.

We clearly need to be more precise about the objectives the developed SDRs would meet. One goal for the developed SDRs seems to be to offer an alternative  currency for cross-border exchange, the volume of which  whould be  mainly driven by the needs of the “real” economy and investments in “real” assets. However, already this seemingly uncontroversial goal raises immediate questions. What is the”real” economy and what is the value of “real” assets?  If other goals are added, such as the balancing of current accounts and the stabilization of exchange  rates the  complexity increases further.  In addition, if we among the goals want to include the role that SDRs could play in the necessary transition to a more sustainable economy and in the support of the development of the living conditions for the billions living in poverty we may reach a complexity level that is outside the reach of what now is possible.  A “big-bang” solution may be attractive in the case of a new financial crisis, but as, for the time being, the “muddling through” scenario is slightly more likely,  a more gradual approach could be favoured.

I have taken with me seven research questions from the workshop. They are in no way the only questions that can be raised and other participants may have other questions they have brought with them home, but I would like to share my seven questions with you for the purpose of promoting a common understanding of the challenges ahead.

1. What are the realistic alternatives to the USD as a reserve currency?

 It is clear that China does not wish the RMB to take over the role as global reserve currency as they are – and probably rightly so – afraid to be caught in the Triffin dilemma and become unable to tackle the domestic interest problem. They may end up having no choice in the matter as history has shown that the switch from one reserve currency to another can be surprisingly fast.

Many see the development of three regional reserve currencies – the USD, the Euro and the RMB. But would this be a stable sloution? It is unlikely, as Carlo Jaeger discusses in his blog input. We need to look more into it and may add some insights from research in other areas to the subject.

The third alternative is a new global reserve currency and given that the other solutions have some drawbacks, this is a solution worth looking into.

2.Who creates the SDRs for commercial use?

Base money are created by central banks, but the overwhelming creation of commercial money is done by banks. Who would create the SDRs, which Governor Zhou is proposing to be used for commercial purposes? If banks would be allowed to create them,  what would be the requests for reserves? There is a big difference between banking systems today as the UK is demanding 0 % in reserves, the US in principle 10 % and China above 20 %.  What would be the optimal liquidity reserves in SDRs if banks are allowed to create them?

3. How could a smooth and gradual transition look like?

Governor Zhou’s proposal is sketchy on this point. He just recognizes the attractiveness of a gradual approach.

4. Would we need capital controls?

The truth is that financial markets with private creation of money have been inherently unstable sinch the 17th century with the exception of the decades after Bretton-Woods. Perhaps we need to reintroduce some controls to reduce speculation and focus the system on the main objectives.

5. Stabilize exchange rates

The status of the USD as rressrve currency is automatically pressing the USD upwards. The introduction of SDRs would relieve the USD from that pressure and rebalance the the exchange rates.  A question: Would even a reintroduction of Bretton Woods in some form or the other be a possibility?

6. Do we need to balance the current accounts?

Keynes saw a rebalancing of current accounts as a major objective of his clearance union. As the exchange rates can be expected to be adjusted at the introduction of SDRs this problem can be expected to be reduced, and especially if a new “Bretton Woods” is introduced.

7. How about the store of value?

The Chinese are expressing concerns about the risk that the US is going to solve its debt problem by printing money. Given the gridlock in the US Congress it is a worry that seems reasonable. The USD was a reserve currency  when Roosevelt unilaterally disconnected the USD from the gold standard and it was a reserve currency when Nixon decided to print money to pay for the Vietnam war. The USD as a store of value is a shaky proposition given the present debt levels. The SDRs could perhaps if connected to the real economy (in a wise way) offer a better store of value. A concern is that commodity markets are highly volatile and manipulated due to speculation and cartels.

Once again -thank you all for your contributions to the workshop and we are looking forward to your input to the white paper!

Best regards

Ulf (Dahlsten)

 

 

 

 

 

Global Imbalances: Equilibrating Exchange Rates vs Quantity Controls

Can we find an equilibrium exchange rate system (e.g. fixed or floating) that might reduce global imbalances or should we rely on penalties, caps or liquidity provisions to create sustainable balance of payments.

For example at the Oct. 22, 2010 G20 summit, Timothy Geithner argued that reducing current account imbalances would strengthen global growth and make it more likely to last. The U.S. pushed to commit each Group of 20 nations to keep its surplus or deficit to less than 4 percent of gross domestic product.  But the manner in which this was to be achieved offered little change from previous measures amounting to deflation in deficit countries and no change in surplus countries.

Criticisms of such policies hark back to the reforms of global imbalances put forth by luminaries such as John Maynard Keynes and Nicholas Kaldor.  Both economists were skeptical of the powers of flexible exchange rates to equilibrate imbalances.  In particular, Kaldor in 1977 found empirically that appreciations of the Japanese and German exchange rates, and even rising labor costs relative to their trading partners, did little to change their increasing share of world trade in 1960s and 70s, typically at the expense of the US and UK. Looking at the history of currency realignments, the success of devaluations in reducing surpluses is variable at best.

Kaldor’s instead proposed a solution that would focus on the terms of trade between manufactured goods and commodities – the raw materials essential to industry. Ordinarily, devaluation will raise a country’s cost of raw materials (if such inputs are primarily imported), create inflation and possibly lead to rising wages.  This would raise the cost of manufactured exports and lower competitiveness. During the period that Kaldor studied, he found that the appreciation of the Japanese and German currency compensated for rising prices of food, industrial materials and oil. This, along with Verdoorn’s law (increasing returns in production and the positive feedback in market share and labor productivity) allowed these countries’ trade surpluses to grow.

Consider today’s currency environment, if China was alone in maintaining a low exchange rate relative to the US dollar, then they would necessarily lower the price of their own manufactured goods (i.e. the price of the ‘value added’ by its processing activities) in terms of basic inputs (food and raw materials).  However this trade off between competitiveness and terms of trade is not occurring because there are many other emerging market nations that are also devaluing their currency, including those that primarily sell commodities, all are hoping to create a competitive edge and develop their manufacturing base through export-led growth.

Kaldor designed a trading system that would balance the manufacturing trade between the highly industrialized nations and prevent the industrially dominating ‘go-ahead’ countries from growing through unrequited exports, at the expense of other industrial countries, effectively stopping them from exploiting their own growth potential and ability to pursue policies of full employment.  Kaldor felt that only with cost push inflation pressures and/or a limited supply of labor (although this was rarely binding due to immigration) would an export-led country have an incentive to ever raise their exchange rate enough to counter their competitive advantage in manufactured exports.

Kaldor’s preferred solution was the institution of a new reserve currency, backed by a basket of commodities.  He called this commodity reserve currency (CRC) his ‘gadget’ and once instituted he believed that it would be an apolitical, automatic stabilizer that would resolve global imbalances, promote even growth and effective demand throughout the world (Kaldor initially took this idea from Benjamin Graham and worked on it with Albert Hart at Columbia University in the 1960s and 70s).

In addition a CRC would create a bufferstock of storable raw materials and allow for the stabilization of their price index over the cycle.  The stockpiling of these goods (located at regional futures exchanges and trading centers) would be paid for by the issuance of the reserve currency (redeemable inventory receipts for the basket).  The targeting of a commodity price index could be done with open market operations – buy the basket and increase the supply of CRC when demand and commodity prices were low, or sell the basket and decrease the supply of CRC when demand and commodity prices were high.  This new currency offered a standard of value that can grow or contract counter cyclically to world trade, and most importantly provide a source of stable income to commodity producers (including the developing world).  Unlike the SDR this currency could be internationally traded by public or private participants and did not require liquidity or mass acceptance to make it valuable.  It would be independent of national currencies, hence exempt from the Triffin paradox, and its supply was endogenous to rising world demand

This new reserve would exist alongside individual sovereign currencies which could peg or float to the international reserve. Importantly, each nation would be free to choose their monetary, fiscal, exchange rate and trade policy with their own citizens’ priorities in mind.

In 1977 Kaldor thought his commodity reserve currency proposal was at least 20 years ahead of its time.  Keynes back in 1943 was far more pessimistic.

“The right way to approach the ‘tabular standard’ [CRC] is to evolve a technique and to accustom men’s minds to the idea through [individual] international buffer stocks. When we have thoroughly mastered the technique of these, which is sufficiently difficult without the further complications of the tabular standard and the oppositions and prejudices which this must overcome, it will be time enough to think again” (Keynes 1943).

Keynes thus took the pragmatic route and instead of finding an equilibrating exchange rate process he proposed the balancing of deficit and surplus reserves through member cooperation and agreement to automatic rules and penalties. His international clearing union (or world central bank) would impose penalties on trade surplus and deficit countries and offer strong incentives for surplus countries to spend their reserves held in excess of their quota. (I can offer details here if requested). Exchange rates would for the most part be fixed with capital controls, though adjustable to equate wage efficiencies across countries and balance trade. The International Clearing Union would finance commodity stockpiles to stabilize individual commodity prices and thereby create a counter cyclical international incomes policy to smooth the world business cycle.

Both the Kaldor and Keynes proposal required a new international central bank (or IMF) and both called their international reserve ‘bancor’.  Kaldor’s was backed by commodities, Keyes’s was not. Kaldor’s was meant to be an automatic stabilizer primarily non discretionary in reserve expansion or contraction, while Keynes’s was much more discretionary and required coordination, penalties, and lender of last resort functions. Both had endogenous reserve supplies, although Kaldor’s was fully backed and Keynes’s was not.

Kaldor thought that he had found a tool that would not only cure global imbalances but would create investment into renewable resources that could sustain the industrialization of the developing world in a steady and sustainable manner without the need for coordination.

It is easy to say that both plans remain futuristic utopian policies. But I believe it is important to understand the mechanisms of each and work out whether they can actually do what they promise, regardless of political viability. And then put them in the tool box for future reference.

Detecting and Responding to Climate Change

The following contribution is based on a talk presented at the Symposium on Natural and Man Made Climate Change of the Royal Swedish Academy of Science in honour of Bert Bolin, in Sigtuna, 21-23 May 2012.  The paper has been submitted for publication in Tellus and is currently under review.

 

Abstract
The statistically significant demonstration of the dominant anthropogenic contribution to global warming has contributed significantly to the public acceptance of the reality of climate change. However, the separation between human induced climate change and natural climate variability on the regional scales of greatest relevance for human living conditions is inherently more difficult, Climate mitigation and adaptation policies must therefore necessarily be designed as the response to uncertain risks. Unfortunately, climate policy has stagnated in recent years through the preoccupation with the global financial crisis. Climate scientists can help overcome the current climate policy impasse through the creation of a new generation of simple, actorbased, system-dynamic models that demonstrate the close connection between the stabilization of the global financial system and effective climate policies. Examples are given of alternative stabilzation policies that can lead either to major recessions and unemployment or to stable economic growth supported by an accelerated decarbonization of the economy.

 

Download the paper:
Detecting and Responding to Climate Change
Klaus Hasselmann Max Planck Institute for Meteorology

The monetary Three Body Problem

Over coffee at the workshop this morning I had some interesting conversations about the “three body problem in global finance”. So there is this idea that we are moving from a Dollar based system towards a system based on the triad of Dollar, Euro and “an Asian currency”. There was a time when the latter was likely to be the Yen, but given the long-lasting depression of Japan and the rise of China, it might well be the RMB. This development raises the problem whether such a system is stable, or what it would take to make it stable.

There may be an important relation with the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem in general equilibrium theory: with three or more goods, any kind of chaotic dynamics is possible. What we are to make out of this in view of a multiple reserve currency system, I don’t know, but forgetting about it does not look like a very sound approach.

Experience has shown that in a system with a single reserve currency, markets and central banks dealing with other major currencies tend to focus on the relation between those currencies and the reserve currency. (“Small” currencies may focus on a major currency of particular relevance to them, the way the Swiss Franc is related primarily to the Euro. Exchange rates with the reserve currency then show long swings – typically lasting a couple of years – around the trend of purchasing parity. Between the non-reserve currencies, this then leads to further random fluctuations. The latter are bounded, however, by the “anchor” provided by the reserve currency.

With several reserve currencies of similar weight, the anchor is missing, and the long swings between different currencies can amplify each other, resulting in chaotic dynamics that can include very large and fast swings – leading to major financial crises.

It is interesting to compare the situation with a famous problem of dynamics arising in physics. In the solar system, the sun is much larger than the planets, and these are sufficiently distant from each other not to start to circle around each other, while their moons in turn are small in comparison with the planets and again sufficiently distant from each other. As a result, the solar system is sufficiently stable to allow for life and human cultures to evolve on planet Earth.

Things are very different if one considers the dynamics of bodies of similar size moving through space. With three and more such bodies, chaotic dynamics is the norm. Anything to be learned about currency dynamics from this?

 

Some Remarks on Governor Zhou’s Suggestion to Reform the International Monetary System

By Armin Haas and Ulf Dahlsten

 

Two Challenges

As a prerequisite for sustainable development of both developed and developing societies, we need sustainable financial markets. We deliberately use this notion in two meanings. The meaning familiar to the business and academic sustainable finance community is the instrumental use of financial markets for bringing about a transition from an ecologically unsustainable “real” economy towards a sustainable one. The other meaning is the long-term resilience/stability/viability of financial markets. Concerning the resilience dimension, we identify two major challenges:

i) The first challenge is that since the breakdown of the Bretton-Woods system and the liberalization of the financial markets, there is no financial mechanism for keeping current accounts balanced. The Euro experience is telling in this respect. Without a mechanism that gives incentives to counteract current account imbalances that occur for whatever reason, current account imbalances tend to fuel themselves and eventually render the whole system unsustainable.

ii) The second challenge is a progressive decoupling of financial markets from the real economy. Several metrics show this phenomenon. The growth rate of many indices measuring assets values, for example stock price, commodity price, or house price indices, was way above the real growth rate of the economic entities the indices are based on. The Bank for International Settlements, for example, follows the volume of cross-border transactions; while transactions for export and import have grown linearly, the purely financial transactions have, after a temporary backlash, continued to swell in a significant way. Such transactions now amount to 98 % of all transactions. (See figure 1) The financial speculation in commodity markets is also mounting, in this case exponentially (See figure 2).

This is a dangerous development as the progressing self-referentiality of financial markets threatens their ability of actually controlling the proper working of the real sector. The fact that five years of on-going financial crisis have not been “sufficient” to substantially change the picture and align the financial and the real sphere again is telling about the magnitude of the problem.

Figure 1: Daily cross-border payments in Billion USD
Source: The Bank of International Settlements (BIS)

 

Figure 2: Number of annual trades by commodity, 1996–2011
Source: Maystre and Bicchetti (2012)

 

Historic Approaches for Dealing with these Challenges

Also in the time of the Gold standard, these two challenges had to be addressed. Between the wars, ongoing problems with destabilizing current account imbalances where are major issue. Keynes was well aware of the fact that for stabilizing the world financial system after the ending of WWII, innovative solutions would be needed.  When conceiving his Bancor as a supra-national reserve currency, he therefore worked out a mechanism for keeping current account imbalances in check.  In the wake of Keynes work, several other proposals, like the work of Kaldor, suggested mechanisms for addressing the current account challenge.

Concerning the coupling of the financial sphere and the real economy, there are basically three approaches and respective traditions for addressing this challenge. One approach is to use precious metals, i.e. silver or gold, for backing currencies. An alternative approach is to use a basket of commodities for the same purpose. This basket could include precious metals, but only to a certain extent. A third alternative is to issue money by buying or using as collateral commercial papers, i.e. financial assets that originate from economic operations in the real sector.

 

After Bretton Woods

Since the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in 1971, the world financial system operates with no mechanism for addressing the two challenges. Instead, two approaches gained widespread acceptance, i.e. monetarism and the idea that financial markets are basically self-regulating. Until the outbreak of the contemporary financial and economic crises, the practical consequence of the dominance of these approaches was that most financial actors, i.e. politicians, regulators, central bankers, and decision makers in the financial sector, did not see a necessity for installing mechanisms for addressing the two challenges that we sketched above. After the outbreak of the financial and economic crisis, the situation has changed. We currently witness the beginning of a debate of how to organize the financial system in the decades to come. One important school of thought suggests that in the decades to come, the US Dollar will loose its role of major world reserve currency, giving way to a multi-polar system in which several regionally dominating currencies will be used as reserve currencies. A possible future world could, for example, see a tri-polar structure using the US Dollar, the Euro (however the Euro will be organized), and the Chinese Renminbi as reserve currencies. However, it is not clear how such a scenario could evolve or be managed. The People’s Bank of China is presently carefully increasing the convertibility of the Renminbi. Many expect that it will be fully convertible in a relatively near future, at the latest when China surpasses the US as the world’s largest economy, something the IMF predicts will happen before 2020. If there is no managed process in place, there is a risk is that there will be an uncontrolled flight from the Dollar to the Renminbi, in practice establishing the Chinese currency as a new reserve currency. Such a disruptive development could create financial instability with unforeseen consequences.

 

The Chinese Proposal

It is important to understand that the proposal that Governor Zhou made in 2009 envisions an alternative future. Under the impression of the contemporary financial and economic crisis, he suggests to create an international reserve currency that is disconnected from individual nations and managed by a global institution. Moreover, this currency should be organized so as to be able to remain stable in the long run. He thus wants to overcome the inherent deficiencies caused by using credit-based national currencies.

A striking aspect of Governor Zhou’s proposal is that he conceives China as a nation that endorses international co-operation when it comes to re-organizing the World financial system. This is in contrast to the view that China will, descriptively speaking, or should, normatively speaking, establish the Renminbi as dominating World reserve currency in the future. Both the descriptive as well as the normative view build on the expectation that China is set to grow into the World biggest economy.

Governor Zhou explicitly builds his proposal on Keynes’ Bancor concept developed in the 1940s. He is well aware of the fact that the creation of an international currency unit along the lines of Keynes’ proposal is a bold initiative that requires extraordinary political vision and courage and will take a long time.

In a pragmatic perspective, Governor Zhou suggests to use a gradual process that is guided by a grand vision and builds on what is currently already established. In particular, he suggests giving the Special Drawing Rights a greater role and broadening the scope of using them with the eventual goal of developing SDR to a point so that they satisfy countries’ demand for a reserve currency.

Governor Zhou does not explicitly discuss how to address the two challenges that we discuss above. He does, however, make it clear that his grand vision includes establishing a stable valuation benchmark. Moreover, he states that the allocation of the SDR can be shifted from a purely calculation-based system to a system backed by real assets, such as a reserve pool.

As Keynes’ original proposal came with an explicit mechanism for keeping current account imbalances in check, and as Governor Zhou envisions establishing a stable valuation benchmark, we think that he is very well aware of the two challenges and the need to explicitly address them. Thus, his proposal is in sharp contrast to the above-mentioned vision of a multi-polar world that comes without established mechanisms for addressing the two challenges.